National and Global Islamic Financial Architecture:
Prolems and Possible Solutions for the OIC Member Countries
25
implications of
maqasid
in a variety of ways. At the broadest level, Abozaid (2010: 67) views it
as a vision that protects and preserves public interests in all aspects and segments of life.
Fulfilling the
maqasid
at this level would imply that an economy should ensure growth and
stability with equitable distribution of income, where all households earn a respectable income to
satisfy basic needs (Chapra 1992). Achieving the objectives of optimal growth and social justice in
an Islamic economy would require universal education and employment generation (Naqvi 1981:
85).
The micro-
maqasid
relates to specific issues arising in the operations and transactions of the
Islamic financial sector. Using various legal maxims, Dusuki and Abdullah (2007) and Dusuki
and Bouheraoua (2011) conclude that prevention and minimizing harm should be a key
objective of an Islamic firm. These would include not engaging in harmful activities such as
selling products that harm the consumer, dumping toxic waste harmful to the environment or
residential areas, engaging in speculative ventures, etc.
Maqasid
at the micro or product level
also implies
Shariah
compliance and fulfilling the objectives of contracts. Kahf (2006) views
maqasid
in transactions as fulfilling the objectives stipulated in contacts. These include
upholding property rights, respecting consistency of entitlements with the rights of ownership,
linking transactions to real life activity, transfer of property rights in sales, prohibiting debt
sale, etc.
Two key principles governing Islamic financial transactions are that financing is closely linked
to the real economy and returns are associated with risks in real transactions. The legal
maxims of ‘benefit of a thing is a return for the liability for loss from that thing’ (
al-kharaj bi al-
daman
) and ‘the detriment is as a return for the benefit (a
l-ghurm bi al-ghunm
) (Majallah
Articles 85 and 87) link ‘entitlement of gain’ to the ‘responsibility of loss’ (Kahf and Khan 1988:
30). The implications of these maxims is a preference for profit-loss sharing instruments and
also that the party enjoying the full benefit of an asset or object should bear risks of the
ownership (Vogel and Hayes 1998).
2.3.1. Islamic Modes of Financing
Traditional Islamic modes of financing can be broadly classified into equity and debt
instruments. While equity instruments are
mudarabah
and
musharakah
, debt-instruments
arise from sale transactions. These fixed-income instruments include
murabahah
(cost-plus or
mark-up sale),
bai-muajjal/murabahah
(price-deferred sale),
istisna/salaam
(object deferred
sale or pre-paid sale) and
ijarah
(leasing).
6
We outline the basic concepts and properties of
these instruments below.
a)
Murabahah/Bay Muajjal
:
Murabahah
is a sale contract at a mark-up. The seller adds a
profit component (mark-up) to the cost of the item being sold. When the purchase is on credit
and the payment for a good/asset is delayed, then the contract is called
bai-muajjal
. A variant
would be a sale where the payments are made in instalments. These contracts create debt that
can have both short and long-term tenors. In these debt contracts, the supplier of the good has
a claim on a fixed amount that must be paid before arriving at a profit.
6
For a discussion on these modes of financing see Ayub (2011) and Usmani (1999).