Improving Public Debt Management
In the OIC Member Countries
35
Audit, transparency and accountability
Once decisions with respect to the institutional form and strategy of the DMO have been taken,
its success depends – among other factors – on its accountability, governance and monitoring
by the political entity in charge of public debt management, in most cases the Ministry of
Finance or Parliament. An efficient governance structure of DMOs depends on a number of
considerations. DMOs have to be institutionalized with a clear mandate. Clearly defined
objectives such as strategic targets and performance benchmarks help to improve
accountability and limit principalagent problems. The Ministry of Finance, parliament or the
respective supervising authority should be endowed with the necessary resources to carry out
their monitoring function.
Both DMOs within the ministry and separate Debt Management Offices (SDMOs) imply that
authority is delegated. In such situations a classical principalagent problem arises: while the
Minister of Finance is responsible for the debt management strategy, its execution is delegated
to the DMO. Due to asymmetric information the Minister of Finance cannot distinguish
whether targets have been missed because of developments outside the control of the debt
manager, or because of insufficient effort or skill of the agent. Agency risk increases with the
degree of separation and autonomy of public debt management from the ministry. To limit
agency problems, it is important to clearly specify the objectives of the DMO such that the
agent’s performance can be measured and to formulate an incentivecompatible contract for
the agent. In addition, to facilitate delegation, public debt management functions should be
consolidated in a single office with a clearly designated head who is directly answerable for the
monitoring entity. If a SDMO is established, a board of directors might bridge the gap between
SDMO and Ministry of Finance. The board might monitor the SDMO, evaluate its performance
visàvis the targets and ultimately sanction its decisions.
Coordination with Macroeconomic Policies
Coordination with fiscal and other public policies
When public debt management is implemented as portfolio management, the DMO follows a
narrow objective function according to which costs are minimized for given risks. Another
view argues that this strategy is inefficient and the objective function should also include the
interplay of public debt management with other public policies. On one hand, the
independence from the political process allows efficiency gains, because debt is managed by
purely economic considerations. On the other hand, if other public policies are not taken into
account, this might not be optimal because the coordination of different public policies might
prove to be beneficial.
The view that debt management is a component of public policy argues that the analysis of
risks and costs should focus on the entire public balance sheet instead of being restricted to its
liability side. This strategy acknowledges currency and interest rate risks and, hence, focuses
on budgetary risks. This form of public debt management aims at reducing financial risks by
guaranteeing that the government can meet its obligations at any point in time. Therefore,
public budget management has to examine the nature of government revenues and cash flows
and try to prevent mismatches between revenues and debt payments. The structure of
revenues and spending – maturity and currency denomination – should be as similar as
possible. Given that tax revenues are usually in domestic currency, this approach implies that
countries should primarily use debt instruments denominated in domestic currency. Examples
of countries following this broader framework for debt management are Australia and New