Background Image
Previous Page  19 / 236 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 19 / 236 Next Page
Page Background

Preferential Trade Agreements and Trade Liberalization Efforts in the OIC Member States

With Special Emphasis on the TPS-OIC

13

tariff may be reduced but not necessarily eliminated. In addition, in a PTA not all trade will be

covered by the agreement, and there are frequently long lists of excluded products (or short

lists of products included). Nevertheless, it is possible to have agreements where full

preferences are introduced in a limited set of products or that partial preferences are intro-

duced in substantially all trade. Key and necessary components of this type of agreement are

the underlying Rules of Origin. Without them, as discussed earlier, it would be possible for

non-members to channel trade from one member to another using the preference in place.

This somewhat vague characterization of PTAs introduces its most distinctive feature - that is

its high degree of flexibility as countries can design the agreement without limited restrictions

or constraints. However, in turn, such flexibility can lead (and frequently has been the case) to

the construction of agreements which are de facto ineffective For example an agreement might

grant preferences on those products where the MFN tariffs are already very low; leading to an

agreement with minimum effects on trade and, consequently, on economic welfare. As will be

discussed later in this report such agreements are only WTO compatible under the Enabling

Clause and as a consequence apply to developing countries. Examples of these agreements are

the Latin American Integration Association (LAIA) or the agreements signed by India with

Mercosur or Chile. Moreover, under this category falls the Global System of Trade Preferences

among Developing Countries (GSTP), a country wide system of partial preferences between

developing countries. The TPS-OIC is also an example of a PTA.

Agriculture One key issue which often arises is whether to include agriculture as part of a

given PTA. From the domestic political economy point of view this can raise challenges arising

from the additional competition by regional partners. The regional partners may be lower-cost

producers or have superior marketing or trade infrastructure. As argued in Chauffour et. al

(2011) the policy dilemma is whether protect the domestic sector, or to subject it to further

competition in the hope that it will respond by undertaking structural and technological

reform enabling it to become competitive regionally and possibly globally. From a political

economy point of view, for many countries, the sector is frequently a sensitive sector owing

due to proportion of the population engaged in agricultural activities; and also because of the

presence of quotas, as well as production and/or export subsidies. Liberalisation of agriculture

in geographically contiguous regional PTAs can lead to realisation of scale economies and

rationalisation of production and investment.

Free Trade Agreements (FTAs)

This is a subset but extremely special case of a PTA. In a FTA, "substantially all" trade must be

covered and full preferences must be granted. Therefore, this agreement constitutes a deeper

level of ambition than a PTA. While agreements notified under the Enabling Clause are not

required to be FTAs; those notified under Art.XXIV of the GATT have to at least match this

characterization. The key feature of an FTA is that each participating country retains control

over their external tariffs while liberalising trade between themselves. Hence as with PTAs in

order to prevent trade deflection, rules of origin are required.