Background Image
Previous Page  16 / 236 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 16 / 236 Next Page
Page Background

Preferential Trade Agreements and Trade Liberalization Efforts in the OIC Member States

With Special Emphasis on the TPS-OIC

10

to respond to competitive pressure. All of this may lead to higher levels of economic activity

and therefore welfare gain.

As each of these effects are likely to be driven by trade liberalisation, then it is natural to

suppose that partial trade liberalisation, partly leads to such gains. To some extent this is likely

to be correct. However, the story becomes somewhat more complicated. Whenever a country

liberalises its trade with a subset of countries (e.g. bilateral liberalisation v unilateral

liberalisation, or bilateral liberalisation v multilateral liberalisation) there are two effects likely

to be present, and which were identified as far back as the 1950s by Viner. These two effects

are trade creation and trade diversion:

Trade Creation

In principle there are two aspects to trade creation. First, suppose that prior to the reduction

of tariffs between countries A and B that there is a product, k, which is produced and supplied

internally within each country and is not traded. Once tariffs are reduced bilaterally country A

has a comparative advantage in that product and therefore it is now exported to country B.

Note that we would expect imports from country A to increase in the product, and for

production in country B to decline. This is the process of (intra-regional) specialization and

trade is occurring where it did not occur before and therefore there has been trade creation.

Second, suppose that B was already importing product k from country A, but the level of

imports was restricted by the tariff. As tariffs are liberalised more trade takes place once again

trade is being created. These effects are an illustration of (i) above, and tend to increase real

GDP in the economy.

Trade Diversion

Now suppose that prior to signing the agreement product k was imported from country C, ie

from a non-partner country. Once A and B sign the agreement it may be possible for country A

to undercut country C in the market of country B. Hence instead of importing the good from

country C, country B now imports the good from A. Here, the source of imports has switched

(hence this is sometimes referred to as supply switching) from C to A. However, if prior to the

agreement country B levied the same tariffs on imports from C and imports from A, and

country B chose to import the good from C, then presumably this is because C was relatively

more efficient than A. So the bilateral agreement between A and B has resulted in a switch of

imports from a more efficient supplier (country C) to a less efficient supplier (country A). In

other words trade has been diverted away from C. Because you are now importing from a less

efficient supplier this tends to decrease real GDP in the economy.

All preferential trade agreements are likely to comprise some mix of both trade creation and

trade diversion. The former is welfare increasing the latter is welfare decreasing. Whether the

agreement overall is welfare increasing or not will therefore depend, in the first instance, on

the relative magnitudes of trade creation and trade diversion respectively. The empiric of this

is taken up later on in this report.