Background Image
Previous Page  32 / 161 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 32 / 161 Next Page
Page Background

Retail Payment Systems

In the OIC Member Countries

18

one of these externalities continues to exist, the market is two-sided, though the intensity of

the externalities may vary across payment systems, countries and even within countries.

6

Adoption externalities relate to the fact that a payment platform with more payment cards

issued is relatively more attractive to merchants than one with fewer cards issued. Similarly, a

payment system with many merchants registered may be more attractive to consumers than

one with fewer merchants. Reaching a minimum scale for success may require years of

investment including much sunk cost. Moreover, there is no guarantee of success, even by

payment systems that would be successful if they reached sufficient scale.

Unarguably, retail payment systems represent a substantial part of the whole economy. For

instance, as early as 2000, Humphrey et al. (2000) estimated that the United States spent $225

billion per year just to make payments, or 3% of GDP.

7

For other countries, the percentage of

GDP is likely to be lower: these countries generally use cheaper instruments than cheques and

the number of non-cash transactions is lower than in the US. Meanwhile, De Grauwe et al.

(2000) do include the cost to the merchant and get a cost of 0.7% of GDP for cash alone. Some

0.2% is borne by banks, leaving 0.5% to be borne by consumers and merchants. Overall these

estimates indicate that the cost of the payment system represents something in the range of

1.5-3% of GDP for developed countries. It is also expected that the cost of the payment systems

in developing countries will be slightly larger. In most cases, this is lower than the cost of

operating cash systems, where the burden is widely distributed as risk, and associated

insurance and security expenditure, to all users and especially small businesses.

Indeed, costs vary significantly across the various instruments. Unfortunately, most of these

costs are hard to measure: they represent processing costs for banks, and handling costs of

merchants, businesses and consumers—none of these are readily obtainable.

8

The impact of

using different instruments can also be large. For example, Humphrey et al. (2000) estimated

that the United States could save 1.25% of GDP in the move from paper cheques to electronic

giro. Similarly, Humphrey et al. (2001) estimate that Norway could save 0.6% of GDP by

moving all of its paper-based instruments to electronic versions. Unfortunately, to the best of

6

The price structure will develop in such a way that both sides have incentives to participate in the market. Rochet and

Tirole (2003) call this a two-sided market. They state that the volume of transaction on and the profit of a platform depend

not only on the total price charged to the parties to the transaction, but also on its decomposition.

7

This huge figure is based on an average cost per non-cash transaction of $2.60 times 87 billion non-cash transactions per

year. It excludes the cost of cash, but it still uses the old check estimate by whom? (66 billion cheques per year, which was

later revised downward by 17 billion.

8

Several authors have tried to estimate costs of the main payment instruments. For example, Humphrey et al. (2003) and

van Hove (2004) give a comprehensive overview of the state of the art in estimating payment costs. Both highlight the

pitfalls and difficulties in obtaining estimates that are comparable across countries.