Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  89 / 213 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 89 / 213 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Agricultural Market Performance:

Creation and Development of Market Institutions

75

Governments and between state and private entities. Alireza Bozorgi, a member of the Iranian

Expediency Council’s committee on agriculture, water and natural resources, has said that the

country “lacks a strategic vision that involves all key institutions…the Ministry of Agricultural

Jihad should coordinate its efforts with the Ministries of industry and trade, energy, economy

and finance as well as with the Central Bank of Iran, seeing that only a coordinated strategy

could pave the way for a healthy growth in the sector.”

121

The Iranian position statement represents progress of a sort, but it addresses the public sector

exclusively and ignores the critical role of non-Government organizations like NOGAMU in

Uganda, and PISAgro in Indonesia. These are the kinds of structures that can increase the

market power of smallholder farmers and link them to the value chains of international

agribusiness companies. Their success depends to a large degree on appropriate Government

policy and institutional reforms.

As many countries’ experience of reforms illustrates, abrupt abolition of subsidies on fuel,

agricultural inputs like fertilizer, and food can lead to civil unrest as well as disruption of

agricultural markets and supply chains. These reforms, though essential, need to be phased in

deliberately and managed carefully. The alternative, as Iran’s experience illustrates, can result

in the huge savings on subsidy expenditures being siphoned off into political activities or

corrupt officials’ pockets rather than used to reinforce market institutions and social welfare

programs. Nigeria’s GES, described above is almost certainly a better model.

The difficulty of coordinating institutions and policies on a regional level is in many ways even

greater than that of achieving coordination within a single country. The potential rewards,

however, may be even greater. Africa is the least-integrated region of the world. Even within

the major trade blocs, intraregional trade accounts for a mere 10% of the total external trade

of ECOWAS and COMESA Member Countries and 15% of that of SADC countries. In North

Africa, the level of integration is even lower: only 2.7% of North African countries’ external

trade is with other North African countries, while in Central Africa, trade among ECCAS and

CEMAC countries is only 1% of Member Countries’ external trade. This compares to 72% for

the EU and 52% in Asia.

122

Trade between countries belonging to different regional groups is minimal, especially since

neighboring countries that are not part of the same trade bloc may impose very high tariffs on

one another. Nigeria and Cameroon share a 2,000-kilometers border, but trade between the

two countries is minimal. Exports from Nigeria, a member of ECOWAS, to Cameroon, a member

of ECCAS and CEMAC, in 2016 amounted to US$233.1 million, or 0.7% of Nigeria’s total exports

of US$35.5 billion. Cameroon’s exports to Nigeria were US$40.8 million, or 1.9% of its total

exports of US$2.1 billion. This is largely explained by high tariffs: to pick one example,

Cameroon’s exports of meat products face a 34.96% tariff in Nigeria and other ECOWAS states,

as against 0% in other ECCAS and CEMAC countries.

123

121

The Iran Project (2013), Iran’s need for agricultural reform, available at

http://theiranproject.com/blog/2013/07/10/irans-need-for-agricultural-reform/ [

Accessed May 2017].

122

NEPAD (2013),

Agriculture in Africa: Transformation and Outlook

, p. 43, Johannesburg: NEPAD.

123

ITC Trade Map (2017), ITC Trade Map, available a

t www.trademap.org

and Market Access Map

www.macmap.org

[Accessed May 2017].