Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  46 / 213 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 46 / 213 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Agricultural Market Performance

:

Creation and Development of Market Institutions

32

economic markets and sectors, provide public goods, and set prices for goods, products, and

services.

2.2 Historical Development of Agricultural & Food Market Institutions

The first records of market institutions specifically interfering in the agricultural and food

market on behalf of authorities can be traced back to early Medieval Europe.

36

The Dutch city

of Gouda, for instance, was granted feudal rights to establish a food market to exclusively trade

cheese, which was actually not produced in Gouda itself but in the surrounding country side.

The growth of agricultural and food market institutions was driven by rapid urbanization and

economic growth, which forced fragmented and inefficient small-scale institutions (e.g. fairs,

markets, and travelling tradesmen) to transform into fixed and interconnected institutions

with a legal and statutory framework.

Early forms of agricultural market institutions secured low food prices and stable food

supplies – especially in times of harvest failure and food shortages - and regulated the

exchange of agricultural products for services and manufactured goods, with local institutions

licensing marketplaces where such trade of agricultural commodities was allowed. A strong

moral duty existed for these market institutions to ensure producers of agricultural

commodities did not hoard more than their immediate needs, preventing from excess profits

or monopoly power. Early market institutions also introduced and ensured compliance with

uniform weights, standards, and grades. An example is the “Assize of Bread,” which

determined the price of grain vis-à-vis the weight of a standard loaf of bread, and which is one

of the earliest examples of a law regulating the agricultural and food market.

Political stability and integration of early modern states as well as a centralization of power

(and, hence, market institutions) led to increased integration of agricultural markets, more

stable supplies of food, and to improved controls of price volatility. Indeed, many early modern

states actively implemented regulations through market institutions for controlling and

guiding the benefits of trade, while supporting market development too.

The introduction of capitalism and mass production during this era also impacted the

agricultural and food market system, transforming the nature, volume, specialization,

geographical range, and size of market channels, particularly food retail, distribution, and

wholesale. Supplying large centers of consumers encouraged traders to respond to price

differences.

Indeed, modern forms of agricultural market institutions date back to the mid-19

th

century. In

Europe, farmer-owned cooperatives came to dominate dairy production in Scandinavia by the

1890s, having crowded out most capitalist firms,

37

and Government-sponsored agriculture

extension services emerged in France, Italy, and the U.K., starting in the 1870s.

In the United States, the Morrill Act of 1862, signed by President Lincoln during the Civil War,

created state colleges "of agriculture and the mechanic arts" in the northern United States,

36

Casson, M. & Lee, J. (2011), “The Origin and Development of Markets: A Business History Perspective,”

Business History

Review

, 85(1), pp 9-37.

37

Persson, K. (2010),

An Economic History of Europe: Knowledge, Institutions, and Growth, 600 to the Present,

pp. 85-87, New

York: Cambridge University Press.