Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  49 / 213 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 49 / 213 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Agricultural Market Performance:

Creation and Development of Market Institutions

35

This overlapped with policy liberalization and deregulation of global trade. The proliferation of

international trade agreements under supervision of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in

the 1990s further opened up global markets and facilitated the integration of developing

countries into global market systems. This resulted in increased private sector investment and

FDI across various stages of market systems, thereby partly substituting the role of traditional

market institutions and the vacuum which emerged after withdrawal from Government

intervention.

However, the openness of markets to international investors in combination with withdrawal

of Government-supported market institutions has resulted in the emergence of large

enterprises that dominate various stages of market systems (e.g. intermediary, distribution,

and wholesale). The result is non-competitive market channels, where the Government is not

in full control, but rather the private sector is.

Hence, more awareness has recently emerged for the need to balance Government

intervention through market institutions with private sector involvement. This is also in

response to the awareness of consumers and companies concerning sustainable development,

reflected in adoption of CSR principles.

52

This brings considerable opportunities and need for

agricultural market institutions as to facilitate the implementation of CSR principles.

2.4 Recent Trends in the Development of Agricultural & Food Market

Institutions

Recent trends in the development of these institutions reflect the general trends of market

institution development as described in the previous section. Promoting agricultural market

was a typical Government activity throughout much of the early 1980s.

53

Expansion of public

sector involvement in agricultural market has been undertaken through the creation of new

market institutions.

54

Indeed, this strong Government interference in agricultural markets is

shown by the proliferation of Government (-supported) institutions such as marketing boards,

cooperatives, unions, and commodity regulation authorities.

55

Objectives of these market institutions primarily concerned regulating inputs (e.g. fertilizers,

seeds, and equipment) through price controls and subsidies, as well as controlling a stable

supply and demand of food commodities with fixed commodity pricing (i.e. below market

levels), public storages and processing, and minimum price guarantees. Imposing quality

standards and grades and regulating (rather “limiting”) private commercial agricultural

activities also belonged to the responsibilities of many agricultural market institutions.

This strong Government interference in the agricultural market and the role of agricultural

market institutions eventually discouraged agricultural producers from innovating as fixed

commodity prices and guarantees created a disincentive for agricultural producers to remain

competitive and operate efficiently. Agricultural production and exports stagnated. Moreover,

52

Van Trijp, H. & Ingenbleek, P. (2010), “Markets, market and developing countries: Where we stand and where we are

heading”, pp. 9-16, Wageningen: Wageningen Academic Publishers.

53

Ibid

54

Poole (2010), “From ‘market systems’ to ‘value chains’: what have we learnt sinc the post-colonial era and where do we

go?,” in Van Trijp, H. & Ingenbeek, P. (eds.),

Markets, market and developing countries: Where we stand and where we are

heading

, pp. 17-22, Wageningen: Wageningen Academic Publishers.

55

Barrett, C. & Mutambatsere, B. (2008), “Agricultural Markets in Developing Countries,” in Blume, L. & Durlauf, S. (eds.),

The

New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

, pp. 2-3, London: Palgrave Macmillan.