Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  125 / 213 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 125 / 213 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Agricultural Market Performance:

Creation and Development of Market Institutions

111

As has become evident, Tunisia has quite a range of market institutions which facilitate the

implementation of its agricultural price support measures and regulations such as subsidized

inputs, guaranteed minimum prices, and direct market intervention. For example;

UTAP has the ability to directly intervene in the market in collaboration with the Inter-

Professional Agricultural Associations and private sector in order to balance supply

and demand of the market, guarantee reasonable prices for the farmers, and ensure

regulatory stock (i.e. control and location of stock per governorate).

SOTUMAG manages the largest wholesale market of Tunisia, where the country’s

circuits of agri-food distribution are consolidated and unified through monitoring and

regulatory enforcement mechanisms. SOTUMAG’s mandate also concerns diffusion of

the standard for prices of products.

Marketing boards have a relatively strong market interference power, as they can

negotiate this price freely, thereby guaranteeing a certain minimum price (i.e. ONH) or

buy common wheat and durum at prices set by the Government while selling domestic

and imported cereals at fixed prices to processing facilities (i.e. OC).

These existing agricultural market institutions in Tunisia have responded to (some of) these

three most urgent challenges. UTAP, for instance, has implemented a pilot project for the

creation of distribution cooperatives to bypass the ever growing number of traders and

intermediaries, enabling small-scale farmers to sell their products directly to the market. In

this context, another example from UTAP is relevant. This example concerns the Kairouan

Governorate, where a private cereals cooperative has been developed under the supervision of

UTAP. After three years, this co-operation made a net profit of about US$107,000 while state-

owned cooperatives lost profit. This can be attributed to the collaboration, trust among

farmers, collectively purchase of inputs, and harmonization and standardization of agricultural

production. It remains politically challenging, however, to give up power of state-owned

cooperatives to private-led cooperatives.

Though not one of the six selected agricultural market institutions, a good practice in this

context is an initiative of one of the line Ministries involved in agricultural market systems (i.e.

Ministry of Investment, Development, and International Cooperation), which has been

developed in collaboration with the World Bank. The program looks to connect small-scale

farmers with markets while simultaneously creating jobs, valorizing what is produced local,

and ensuring reliable prices to small-scale farmers. This is done by developing coordination

institutions (or “units of transformation”) and private-sector cooperatives to transform

commodities locally and hence add value in the rural areas. However, distribution to markets

remains an issue due to lack of infrastructure and legal issues arise as a change of law is

required to transfer public investment to the private cooperatives.

Some of the priorities of Tunisia’s post-revolution agriculture and fisheries development plan

2016-2020 concern addressing the fragmentation of the sector, the creation of new

mechanisms to exploit agricultural land, and improving governance practices by means of (the

creation of new) professional and civil-society organizations and coordination mechanisms,

214

which could include the creation of new market institutions.

214

WTO (2016),

Tunisia Trade Policy Review Report by the Government

, Geneva: World Trade Organization.