Previous Page  28 / 214 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 28 / 214 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Transnational Transport Corridors

In the OIC Member Countries: Concepts and Cases

14

2.5. Economic Factors

2.5.1.

Corridors, trade and economics

Between transport corridors and trade there is a mutual relation, fostering each other. They

are connected in the same way as the connection between economics and infrastructure.

According to (Rietveld and Bruinsma, 1998) in the introduction of their book, economic

development is the result of transport infrastructure. It leads to increased productivity, lower

transport costs, affects trade relationships and the location of production factors. According to

Banister and Berechman (2001) if investment political and institutional conditions are met,

beneficial economic development will take place. (COMCEC, 2016) equally points at the

interaction between economics and transportation. “As most of the transportation textbooks

underline, transportation is a derived demand. People use transportation services to go work,

to visit their relatives and friends, to go shopping, etc. That is why, the change in the

transportation activities can be used as a proxy for changes in overall economic activities. The

rise in the container traffic, for example, is a perfect indicator of the growth in the trade and

manufacturing industry. On the other hand, the change in the air passenger traffic can reveal

how some high-tech and service based industries, which rely more on air travel, are

performing.”

Economic theory of international trade started with David Ricardo's theory of comparative

advantage. It says that trade between two entities is based on comparative advantages. About

one century later Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin (Gandolfo, 2014) analyzed that trade between

two entities is based on comparative advantages and factor endowments of the production

factors, being labor, land and capital. A country will export products that use its abundant and

cheap factor of production. This country will equally tend to import products that use the

countries' scarce and dear factor(s).

Illustrative is the so-called flying geese effect (Carruthers, 2003), that occurred between 1960

and 1990 in East Asia. This is the effect of a rapid expansion of the industrial complex

combined with a strong focus on international trade (Akamatsu, 1962), leading to a steep

increase in economic growth, slowing down at a very high (>10% p.a.) economic growth rate .

In East Asia, the first wave of growth was in Japan, followed by a second wave of the "Four

Tigers" - Hong Kong, the Republic of Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan. The third wave occurred in

Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand. Followed by the transition economies of China and Vietnam.

The first wave triggered the next one because Japan needed additional production capacity to

meet the high demand for its products, leading to outsourcing. This led to economic growth in

the economies around Japan, and the effect repeated and spread further on. Trade and

economic development went hand in hand (Mascelluti, 2015), and were followed by

institutional, political and technological changes. (Joshua, 2017) highlights the importance of

international trade to the Chinese economy. Carruthers (2003) distinguishes:

Outward oriented highly accessible countries, having higher incomes, high technology

and services based economies, high transport volumes and competitive logistics costs;