Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  59 / 213 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 59 / 213 Next Page
Page Background

Improving Agricultural Market Performance:

Creation and Development of Market Institutions

45

and exporters’ activities, so that, “Exporters are now free to purchase direct from farmers. The

system of débloquage – the need to have Government approval before making a sale in the

export market – has also been scrapped.”

89

“The main advantage to farmers of the free market system is that they tend to receive a higher

proportion of the prevailing international market price. The margin taken by intermediaries

and exporters is relatively small as they are in competition with each other. Generally, farmers

in countries with free market systems have been getting, typically, anything from 80% to 85%

of the FOB price for their cocoa, while those working under a caisse or board system have

usually received less (and sometimes far less) than 50%.”

90

Although liberalization enabled farmers to capture a larger share of export proceeds from their

crop, it also increased their vulnerability when prices declined. With the abolition of CAISTAB,

the cocoa trade “reverted to a spot market, which led to increased volatility.”

91

Abolition of CAISTAB had other adverse consequences, which included:

A decline in quality of product delivered to exporters, since the authorities did not

provide adequate time and support for other mechanisms or entities (either a state or

a private quality control and certification agency, such as an exporters’ association) to

emerge to replace the quality control function previously exercised by CAISTAB;

Potential exposure of buyers to greater risk of contract non-performance absent the

performance guarantees previously provided by CAISTAB;

Greater risk of exploitation of farmers by traders, especially in areas where the

quantities of cocoa produced are insufficient to support more than one

intermediary…“Farmers may…be enticed by intermediaries to take generous advances

as credit against future crop deliveries, and thus become indebted to them.”

92

Research by Wilcox and Abbott (2004) indicates an increase in market power

exercised by multinational exporters following liberalization. “It appears that the

Government continues to extract rents from its large world market share, but

following liberalization those rents are shared with multinational exporters. The

markups, [which] include export taxes, range from 30 to 36%... similar to actual export

taxes charged by the Ivory Coast Government prior to structural reforms…[Data]

suggest the Government still sees and seeks to exploit market power, but that it is now

shared with the multinationals.”

93

If true, these findings would indicate that large companies are the main beneficiaries of

liberalization and that neither farmers nor Government have benefited to any great extent. In

the event, Côte d’Ivoire’s experiment with liberalization was short-lived: just 12 years after it

89

INTRACEN (2001),

Cocoa: A Guide to Trade Practices,

pp. 27-28, Geneva: International Trade Center.

90

Ibid

91

Arvanitis, Y. (2014), “Building commodity trade infrastructure in West Africa: bringing “price” back to its source,”

available a

t https://www.afdb.org/en/blogs/measuring-the-pulse-of-economic-transformation-in-west- africa/post/building-commodity-trade-infrastructure-in-west-africa-bringing-price-back-to-its-source-13320/ [

Accessed

July 2017].

92

INTRACEN (2001),

Cocoa: A Guide to Trade Practices,

pp. 27-28, Geneva: International Trade Center.

93

Wilcox, M. & Abbott, P. (2004), “Market Power and Structural Adjustment: The Case of West African Cocoa Market

Liberalization,” Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual

Meeting, Denver, Colorado, August 1-4, 2004, available at

http://www.agecon.purdue.edu/pdf/Wilcox%20Abbott%20%20Market%20Power%20and%20Cocoa%20Markets.pdf

[Accessed July 2017].